California’s Zero Emission Vehicle Goal a Boost to Innovation

California’s Zero Emission Vehicle Goal a Boost to Innovation

California’s recent goal to have 100% Zero-Emission Vehicles (ZEV) by 2035 represents a big opportunity for innovation in related services. An Executive Order by Governor Newsom continues aggressive leadership in California by focusing on vehicle emissions. California has focused on vehicle emissions, which are over 20% of its Greenhouse Gas Emissions, with AB 1803 and AB 32 and former Governor Brown’s Executive Order to have 5 million EVs by 2030. These executive orders are actually directed toward the Air Resources Board to create the rules to achieve the stated goals.

There are two thoughts around this. One, it isn’t much faster than we were already going and Second, it supports investment in innovative charging services.

It is impressive but fairly slow. Why couldn’t we do this much faster?  With over 15 ZEVs on the market, more than double that in Plug-in Hybrids, and 10 more ZEVs arriving in 2021 there are plenty of models. Tesla has outlined the road to a sub $100 per kWh battery and several light-duty trucks will be coming on the market.  I would have liked to see a more aggressive approach that would have rewarded early innovators more.

The most important takeaway is that this does set the stage for innovation around ZEVs. Commonly vehicle innovation is associated with large OEM’s like Ford and Toyota, while there are companies shaking that up like Tesla, most don’t have the patient financial backing to compete.  The big innovation is going to be around supporting this goal. What does that entail?  New “fueling” infrastructure, charging and hydrogen, that needs development and user education. Tesla built a Fast Charging network that has supported their growth, it is easy to imagine OEMs and others investing in ones for new cars.  

There are several behaviors and preferences EV owners exhibit that could be opportunities for developing charging with auxiliary services.  Putting Fast Chargers (50 kw or greater) in shopping centers or concierge charging like free wire are two examples of possibilities. This EO gives startups a stronger position against skepticism when seeking investment. I am really looking forward to seeing what innovations come out of this. 

Thomas Hall

ABOUT THE AUTHOR

Thomas is the Executive Director of CleanStart. Thomas has a strong background in supporting small businesses, leadership, financial management and is proficient in working with nonprofits. He has a BS in Finance and a BA in Economics from California State University, Chico. Thomas has a passion for sustainability and a commitment to supporting non-profits in the region.

CleanStart Sponsors

Weintraub | Tobin, Moss Adams, River City Bank, GreenbergTraurig

BlueTech Valley, PowerSoft.biz, Revrnt, Synbyo, Califronia Mobility Center

Microgrids a Hot Topic–Again

Microgrids a Hot Topic–Again

There has been an explosion in interest about microgrids and what they can do in the past decade.  But there are also concerns about what some unintended consequences might be.  Ironically, the electric utility business started from a collection of microgrids, but the enormous economies of scale drove the industry to a massive consolidation and growth, while dramatically dropping prices charged to users.  (For those wanting more background, skip to the end of this blog.) The question debated now is whether those enormous economies of scale have with the advent of new technology diminished substantially.  Some things are clear.  

  1. An aggregate of small sources of generation that inject power back into the distribution grid can, if using a large enough portion of the capacity of the distribution grid, destabilize that grid.   
  2. The full benefits of microgrids will not be achieved unless those microgrids are managed and coordinated.  
  3. Microgrids when buffered with storage are more likely to be beneficial in net terms.  
  4. The continued installation of microgrids and connecting them to the main grid will create a need to rebuild the main grid in ways to accommodate power flows in and out of these microgrids.  
  5. Connection charges for microgrids likely need to be mostly a fixed cost per month to reflect the reality of the main grid being used mostly for backup and sharing of excesses.  
  6. If done well, microgrids can avoid the costs otherwise necessary for expanding the grid
  7. With the recent power outages, the perceived benefits of microgrids for reliability and resilience have increased.

So some things can go well, others can go wrong.  Microgrids are likely here to stay, so the question is how to create more positive than negative outcomes. That is a goldmine for new business opportunities.  (Check out Wikipedia on what a Microgrid is.)

The key seems to be making microgrids smart.  Most of the concerns with microgrids would seem to disappear if managers of the distribution system were able to see and control what the microgrids are doing.  That begs the question of whether there will be or should be one or more “Independent Distribution Operators” of IDOs functioning like the current ISOs for the high-voltage part of the grid.  

Here then are some business opportunities to consider for a new world of hundreds or thousands of microgrids operating in harmony with each other and the larger grid.

  1. Invent a better suite of software to manage microgrids and communicate with the ISO (several systems already exist).
  2. Create an Independent Distribution Operations business and sign on as many microgrids and distribution systems as possible.
  3. Create better network interface hardware to ease the job of interacting with the grid (also many of those on the market already)
  4. Invent a less expensive switch to reconnect a microgrid to the macrogrid after a disconnection.  Opening the switch is automatic and easy.  Reclosing seems to be more of a problem and so most small microgrids depend on manual reclosing.
  5. Creating a standard set of protocols for microgrid management and requirements for microgrids to interface properly with the larger grid
  6. Come up with a convincing case as to what the distribution system connection charge should be, considering all positive and negative effects of a microgrid
  7. Create a microgrid network center business, monitoring and controlling a large number of microgrids through proprietary and secure communication links, and providing billing services
  8. Expand the scope of microgrid management software to include demand management, all under the term “Virtual Power Plants”.
  9. Invent the best way to rebuild the distribution grid so that it is more compatible with two-way power flow (and it may involve what is called a “ring bus” architecture)

These are just a few of the wealth of possibilities the microgrid “rush” may provide to entrepreneurs.  To learn more, join the MeetUps we will have October 29 and December 3.  We will have a number of speakers each time to provide their insights on microgrids. 

For those who want more background:

In 1974, Dow Chemical Company was pushing several states (especially in California where they had some big plants) to adopt changes to utility laws to promote this new thing called “cogeneration” at industrial sites, and to allow the power produced at one site to be sold to nearby businesses.  Dow even talked about a coalition of several businesses installing cogeneration and sharing the output among them.  Why was Dow doing this?  It wanted to cut its power costs dramatically.  It wanted to insulate itself from power shortages it saw coming.  No one called this a microgrid, but that is what it was.  The utilities fiercely opposed the idea, as did the CPUC at the time.  They saw it as a threat to the way utilities were virtually guaranteed to recover their investments in generation and the way the costs of those investments were divvied-up among users.  If industrial customers could generate their own power, who would pay their share of the utilities’ costs that were included in the industrial rates?

Nothing happened in 1974, but the idea kept coming back as more and more users saw the rules and regulations governing utility service as outdated and a roadblock to better ways to generate and distribute power.  Many of these rules originated around 1920 when the concern was about “destructive competition” among utilities.  It may sound very strange to be concerned about too much competition, but there was a logic behind it.  A hundred years ago, the technology for generating and distributing electricity was improving rapidly.  As a result, expensive equipment that was state-of-the-art at the time it was built was obsolete in a few short years when a newer technology could provide power so much cheaper.  The result was that utilities wanted to charge a price for power that would recover their costs quickly so that as the new technology arrived it would not jeopardize the investment in the older technology.  Logical, but ill-fated.  Raising prices simply made the newer technology look even more attractive.  So why buy the expensive stuff?  String up some more wires and give me the cheaper stuff! In essence, create competing grids.  Looking at it, the concerns in 1920 were not so different than those in 2020.  

Well, cities a hundred years ago were effectively the regulators of utilities.  Utilities needed to use public rights-of-way to string up the wires.  The cities didn’t want to see the maze of wires along streets blot out the sun, so they started applying the brakes to the “gold rush” atmosphere. And doing it in very different ways depending on the city.  So, a deal was struck, one which the utilities themselves originated.  First, make utility regulation a state matter, not one done by the cities.  (“We need uniform and consistent rules; not the current patchwork!”)  Second, utilities would agree to recover the costs of their investments over a long period, such as thirty years, rather than much shorter terms.  This would make for much lower rates.  (“If we are assured we can recover our costs, then we can recover them more slowly to the benefit of all ratepayers.”)  Third, the state regulator would oversee all the capital investment decisions of utilities (that would be guaranteed to be recovered) and approve rates for all customers.  Fourth, utilities would be given exclusive territories so that no one could undercut them.  No more competition, except in areas at the fringe which were not yet served.  (“We are natural monopolies!”)

This compromise held together for half a century, but eventually, the tidal wave of innovation began to overwhelm the quaint idea of public regulation of natural monopolies in the public interest.  Innovation became the enemy, something to be resisted because it upset too many apple carts.  But the innovations were so appealing, the resistance was hard to maintain.   Finally, in the California deregulation law in 1996 (along with similar steps in a few other states), utilities were compelled to exit the business of owning and operating generation assets.  The recovery of their costs would no longer be guaranteed going forward.  BUT the difference between what the utilities got from selling off generation assets and what was on the books yet to be recovered of the utilities’ original investment in those assets COULD be collected from ratepayers.  This is where the notion of “stranded costs” originated.  (“We told you years ago these costs were OK, but now they are not.  Oops. Let’s do the honorable thing and let you collect from ratepayers the difference between the market value of those assets now and the remaining unrecovered amounts still on your books. And we will make sure the ratepayers have no choice.”)  This approach was expanded to include charging any customers so bold as to decline using the full services of the utility an “indifference charge”.  Sounds harmless, but it means paying for things a customer is not using because that customer did use them in the past and utilities made big investments to serve those customers.  Now customers wishing to disengage in part from the grid are causing concern once again about paying for assets no longer as useful as they once were.

(1) In reality, this whole problem originated with telephone companies.  Electric utilities fell into the same debate and so many of the solutions that had been invented for telephone companies were then applied.

Thomas Hall

ABOUT THE AUTHOR

Gary Simon is the Chair of CleanStarts Board. A seasoned energy executive and entrepreneur with 45 years of experience in business, government, and non-profits.

CleanStart Sponsors

Weintraub | Tobin, EYBlueTech Valley, Revrnt, Moss Adams, PowerSoft.biz

College of Engineering & Computer Science at Sacramento State

FERC Order 2222 Opening up DER to Wholesale Market

FERC Order 2222 Opening up DER to Wholesale Market

FERC directs regional grid operators to revise their tariffs to establish DERs as a category of market participants. While this does not immediately change the landscape, the new rules could provide an opportunity for smaller generation from companies like Helios Altas and Wind Harvest International to be used in DER projects.  

Distributed energy resources have been hampered historically by being too small to justify operating on the Energy Grid. Being able to operate on the Grid allows for a smaller grid to buy and sell energy in the larger market.  This is important for DERs to make financial sense and for their reliability.  Currently, many Grids and energy markets have financial barriers that make smaller energy generation uncompetitive. 

Overall this should increase energy competition and grid reliability. In California, there still are major obstacles in connecting and interacting effectively with the Grid.  

Learn more about the FERC ruling here.